[Addendum: Tweaked on 17 February 2015: de-simplification of explanation of high-powered money creation and destruction processes in the interests of accuracy (brevity can mislead).]
Now to Grexit, a.k.a. Greece’s possible exit from the Euro and Eurozone. I’m
not going to trawl mainstream articles as I did in the last post, as their
narrative is unanimous on one key point, “Syriza has to [insert preferred prescription here] to get Greece growing again.”
The disagreement is on how. The why is not examined, for reasons
I explored in my last post.
Syriza is a party of hope for those
bearing the horrible weight of austerity. The party’s electoral success is an historic
event. It is the first time, certainly in decades, that a non-mainstream and very young party (DOB 2004) has defied mainstream opprobrium to sweep to power in Greece. It calls itself a “radical
left” party, but seeing as Syriza campaigned on staying in the Euro and
Eurozone and that it wants growth, this label is more theatre than substance, regardless of its composition of various smaller left-wing parties. Syriza’s
promises on a minimum wage (the UK and US have that), the reinstatement of pensions,
more transparent politics, renationalisation etc. are not particularly radical historically speaking. In other words, they are what we might
call centre-left policies (with renationalisation being an exception, though still
hardly radical). Perhaps the reason the “radical” label goes uncontested in the media is due in part to how right wing consensus has become, and also to the party’s open defiance of the Troika, its willingness
to speak its truth to power and vociferously reject the austerity narrative so
favoured by Germany, Finland, Holland and others. But I do not want to get
bogged down in that swamp of pedantry about neoliberalism, right- and
left-wing politics, thrift, debt obligations, etc. Others do that far better than
I care to: all of it stays within the mainstream’s preferred narrative of paying
back debt no matter what, perpetual economic growth as an imperative, and never
questioning the underlying system.
A little on Grexit briefly before I get
to the meat. Syriza campaigned on staying in the Euro, but can they do so and
defy Germany, Brussels, the Troika and a host of others? Can the powers ranged
against Greek defiance allow Greece to defy and succeed? Surely they have to stamp
down hard on Greece to discourage Spain, Ireland, then Italy and others from acting on similarly “radical”
ideas that are favoured by their populations. In the other corner, Syriza wants
to stay true to their anti-austerity programme, so they must defy. If they buckle and continue with austerity, they were a
waste of the electorate’s time and hope, and the fascist Golden Dawn party are
guaranteed to make hay in that bitter sunshine. My sense is that Syriza
politicians are passionately and ideologically committed to their programme,
and thus will not buckle.
So something’s got to give. Germany has
made it plain they don’t fear Grexit, but I suspect this is a bluff. If Greece
exits and makes a decent fist of life outside the Euro’s embrace, this will encourage the
others. (And Germany has a small but growing and vocal anti-Euro segment while
around 75% of the public does not trust the mainstream press.) This means that
all efforts would be
made to turn the country into something resembling a failed state. On the other
hand, there’s Russia waiting to adopt the abandoned baby (China, Brazil,
India?), so Greece might be tempted away from the Euro should circumstances coalesce
in that direction, as I think they will. So, in other words, I think Grexit is
coming sooner or later and believe it will be messy.
What I want to examine here in more detail
is what can be accomplished within
the current money system and broader growth-based paradigm, primarily by Greece
but by extension any other nation. My operating assumption is that the economic
growth required by capitalism is over, and that this fundamental situation is
causing constant economic and political disruptions across the globe. The
reasons for this are varied, but primary among them are:
1. Automation blocking the flow of money through the economy, and attendant weak wages are contributing to anaemic demand and insufficient purchasing
power
2. The bumpy peak oil phenomenon
3. Consumerism losing its appeal at the edges (and increasingly in the centre)
4. Peak debt in the private sector a.k.a. tapped-out consumers = insufficient purchasing power (see
below)
5. The decline of ecosystem health across the planet.
While each factor receives sporadic attention
from the mainstream media as isolated issues, it is their interconnected, cumulative
effects and profound implications that are studiously overlooked. The powers
that be are systemically required to continue to flog this dead-horse system to
mincemeat for fear its death spells their demise before they reach sufficient escape velocity and fully decouple from the hoi palloi. A delusion on their part no doubt, but I think we all know how hard
it is to drop cherished delusions, especially those we believe define us.
Given these conditions, Greece
can accomplish very little indeed within or outside the Eurozone, since neither location changes any one of them. Even leaving these vital issues to one side, as a member of
the Eurozone Greece cannot raise money by its own fiat, as that power has
effectively been ceded to the ECB: when a member state’s debt exceeds 60% of
GDP it may no longer issue its own bonds. Greece is at around 175%. In effect, Greece needs permission from the Troika
to pay out pensions at the level that makes sense to it, to pay teachers and police
the higher wages it believes they deserve, to invest in infrastructure
development etc. Being granted permission to take on more debt to pay off existing debts comes
with a whole raft of neoliberal demands that rule out such state largesse. Yanis
Varoufakis, Greece’s finance minister, has put forward a “Modest Proposal”
that, riddled with the language of perpetual growth, suggests debt swaps to get the ball rolling again. However, considering the country’s anti-austerity ambitions, its hostility to the
Troika but loyalty to the perpetual-growth paradigm and the overlooked boundary conditions, not only are such band-aid
measures falling on deaf ears, they will fall short of producing the
desired effects, even though a short bounce back from the depths of a very nasty economic depression is achievable. Should this New-Deal proposal be green lighted by Russian backing and thus outside the Eurozone, the boundary conditions do not change. I am not aware of any plans to change the money system itself, though a proposal has recently been made (German article) to that end by Professor Franz Hoermann and Sarah Hassel-Reusing.
So, these are the current rules of the money
game, and the Modest Proposal sticks to them, Euro or Drachma. Money is created as debt one way or the other. Interest-bearing debt in this model is backed (sustained, kept going)
by expanding economic activity, not gold or other single physical resource, though cheap oil is of course critical to strong growth. If there is too-low, zero or negative growth, the debt-money system implodes, i.e. recessions, depressions and anaemic growth are invariably Bad Things. I examined this in my
last post from a narrowly money-system angle, I want to examine it here from a crude, structural
angle to make a very simple point. I’ll start by sketching the economy as a whole then proceed to some
thought exercises.
A modern economy is basically composed of a public (state) sector and
private sector at the broad, macro level.
There is, in keeping with this, both state debt and private debt.
Following from that there is high-powered money and bank money.
Both are brought into existence as interest-bearing debt one way or the other.
A state creates new high-powered money when it repays its debt. Private debt is incurred when commercial banks create new bank money (issue loans) to firms and individuals.
High-powered money resides in central-bank
accounts held at commercial banks. These accounts are currently awash with
high-powered money after the various tranches of quantitative easing. This
money represents, theoretically speaking, the “reserves” against which commercial
banks are said to issue new bank money via loans to private firms and individuals (fractional
reserve banking, though banks in Canada and the UK are allowed to loan money into existence against no reserves, i.e. how it happens in the real world is different).
If banks don’t create bank money as loans, high-powered money does not lead, as it were, to more bank money via lending. More simply, it does not reach the consumer. This system feature lies behind all
the talk of getting banks lending again.* Commercial bank lending is how our
economies are kept lubricated.
Both sectors are thus always indebted, because money is
created as debt in both. One corollary of this is that if all debts were repaid tomorrow morning, there would be no (bank) money in
the economy (about 97% of the money supply). Money is debt. However, there is nuance. I.e., commercial bank money disappears from the economy as commercial loans are repaid, while high-powered money is added when government repays its debts (government debt is replaced with high-powered money).
The relationship between central and commercial banks thus mirrors (slightly) that between oxygen-emitting plants and oxygen-breathing animals, only the relationship is nowhere near 50-50, but about 3-97. The trick is how money is moved through the economy to effect economic activity (wages, buying and selling) and how to keep the relationship between that movement and the overall money supply on the one hand balanced with economic activity and growth on the other (i.e. controlling inflation/deflation). We can’t just spend money into existence with total abandon without somehow destroying it too; the money supply would balloon far beyond what economic activity could bear. The system is designed with this in mind: debt repayment removes bank money from the economy, taxes and selling government debt remove high-powered money from the economy. However, there is always interest to pay, and that requires exponential economic growth: one systemic effect of interest is that there is never enough money available to cover the interest owed. This creates a musical-chairs atmosphere of constant competition, where survival tends to be about being the biggest, i.e. always growing, always increasing profits and market share. And this dynamic dutifully adheres to the state (or civilisational) project of Human Ascent.
So, were money not created as debt, it would be printed (or spent) into existence, as a government might do faced with the thought experiment below. But I think most of us know how taboo that is in real-world circumstances. It should also be apparent why the problem of growth is such an intractable problem, institutionally speaking.
(As an aside, if you think your money is yours, that because your current account is in the black and you owe nothing to anyone you are thus not debt, ‘your’ money is nevertheless owed by someone to a bank somewhere and is thus someone’s debt. To make matters yet more counterintuitive, money at the bank is in fact the property of the bank. You are allowed to use ‘your’ money while the bank deems it permissible for you to do so. Banks may close their doors during a bank run, for example. (Remember the Cyprus bail in?) The system is more important than the individuals of which it is composed.)
The relationship between central and commercial banks thus mirrors (slightly) that between oxygen-emitting plants and oxygen-breathing animals, only the relationship is nowhere near 50-50, but about 3-97. The trick is how money is moved through the economy to effect economic activity (wages, buying and selling) and how to keep the relationship between that movement and the overall money supply on the one hand balanced with economic activity and growth on the other (i.e. controlling inflation/deflation). We can’t just spend money into existence with total abandon without somehow destroying it too; the money supply would balloon far beyond what economic activity could bear. The system is designed with this in mind: debt repayment removes bank money from the economy, taxes and selling government debt remove high-powered money from the economy. However, there is always interest to pay, and that requires exponential economic growth: one systemic effect of interest is that there is never enough money available to cover the interest owed. This creates a musical-chairs atmosphere of constant competition, where survival tends to be about being the biggest, i.e. always growing, always increasing profits and market share. And this dynamic dutifully adheres to the state (or civilisational) project of Human Ascent.
So, were money not created as debt, it would be printed (or spent) into existence, as a government might do faced with the thought experiment below. But I think most of us know how taboo that is in real-world circumstances. It should also be apparent why the problem of growth is such an intractable problem, institutionally speaking.
(As an aside, if you think your money is yours, that because your current account is in the black and you owe nothing to anyone you are thus not debt, ‘your’ money is nevertheless owed by someone to a bank somewhere and is thus someone’s debt. To make matters yet more counterintuitive, money at the bank is in fact the property of the bank. You are allowed to use ‘your’ money while the bank deems it permissible for you to do so. Banks may close their doors during a bank run, for example. (Remember the Cyprus bail in?) The system is more important than the individuals of which it is composed.)
The reason we constantly hear of debt mountains
during busts (but not booms), is because low growth inhibits commercial banks from issuing and consumers and private firms from
taking on new debt (tapped-out consumers). The system stops functioning as debt repayments gradually exceed
earnings throughout the economy. Low, zero or negative growth and debt-as-pain are thus synonymous,
hence the mantra Growth is Good. When the economy is growing, debt is invisible or not generally problematic at national and international scale. When it is contracting, debt becomes an issue.
After quantitative easing, poor economic growth in the ‘real’
economy of manufacturing and widget production means banks increasingly seek
their profits by gambling high-powered money on the stock and
commodity markets, hence that is where we currently see very visible growth, or bubbles. This means the financial sector rises and falls in a volatile way while everyone else
suffers worsening malaise. What to do?
Back to Greece. Syriza’s solutions stay
within the system and broader paradigm. They want to swap out painful debt for less painful debt to
free themselves to stimulate their economy by directing purchasing power via restored
pensions, public-sector salary increases and infrastructure investment directly
into the pockets of consumers, thus bypassing commercial bank lending. The consumers
will then dutifully go out and buy with renewed abandon, thus collectively causing
an uptick in GDP. This will boost business confidence, which will lead to banks again seeing
profit on the other end of issuing credit to businesses and individuals, and we
return to normal. Après le bust, le boom!
This looks relatively sound on paper and would no doubt conjure a recovery from the bottom (not in itself a bad thing considering the suffering of the Greek people),
but let’s look at this (old) idea in light of the boundary conditions I listed
above. To do so we’ll start with some simple thought experiments that,
hopefully, will bring into relief important economic distinctions between the
public and private sectors.
Imagine that all commercial manufacture,
retail, food production and distribution, i.e. the entire private sector, is now
automated and requires no human labour whatsoever. All that remains for humans to
do is teach, police, put out fires etc., all paid for by the state. What
happens to money flow in this bizarre scenario? The state pays money into
people’s pockets, they buy stuff over the internet that is delivered by
driverless vehicles to their door. From whom do they buy? The owners of the
means of production who continue to attach price tags to their goods and services. So money flows from state coffers through consumers’ pockets and on to the owners of capital. Either the state taxes back that money 100% to
pay its workers next month, or it borrows and borrows and borrows, going deeper and deeper
into debt. Private individuals do not exchange money
among themselves at all in this scenario, so the number of times money changes hands is one:
from consumer to owner of corporation. Money flows straight to the owners of
capital who earn pure profit, more or less (I’m leaving out the costs of raw
materials, utilities and land for the sake of argument). Therefore, the only
point at which the state can realistically exact tax is from the owners of
capital.
There’s an obvious pointlessness to the
above highly fantastical sketch. Of course, I haven’t added banking and interest rates nor considered who builds those websites etc. because it
doesn’t illuminate my central point, which is this: What balance of public and
private economic activity is healthy for an economy? This is of course the stuff of
endless and heated debate, but it should be obvious that it can’t be 100%
state. I’ll repeat and italicise that: it
can’t be 100% state.
Back to the boundary conditions. The
commercial sector needs fewer and fewer human workers to produce the abundance
of consumer goods there is not enough effective demand (purchasing power) to
consume. The environment cannot cope with the amount of resource depletion
consumerism is exacting on it. More and more people are unsatisfied with
consumerism. Peak debt, peak oil, peak other stuff are coming home to roost. In short, demand is too
weak for the system’s perpetual-growth needs. If the state stimulates demand via direct spending
(not via commercial bank lending), will increased consumer spending lead to
meaningful and secure private sector jobs for a sufficient number of people? Or
will corporations’ increased profits resulting from this state largesse free
them to rationalise, invest in new automation technology and further increase
their profits? Will ecosystems allow this game to go on indefinitely? Will ordinary folk be forever enthralled by the hollow allure of consumerism as ecosystems fail, as their hunger for authenticity and community grows?
I have worked in the automotive sector
as a translator and translated documents that detail how wages are the only cost companies can tweak
(downwards) to increase profits. Staff are an unwanted overhead best minimised.
The competition is very fierce in the automitive sector, and no doubt elsewhere. If
Corporation A doesn’t downsize to stay price competitive, Corporation B will
and then eat into A’s market share via lower prices. As this pattern increases and meaningful, well-paid work disappears, the state will be under pressure to take up the
slack more and more so as to furnish consumers with enough purchasing power to
buy what is on sale. If they
want it. If the planet can cope. If Neoliberalism permits or yields to Neokeynesianism.
Now imagine the energy problem is
attacked with vigour. Oil and other fossil fuels are no longer needed. There is suddenly an abundance of cheap, renewable energy. Now is sustainable growth possible? Not really. Cheap,
green energy does not change the spectre of technological unemployment, in fact
it makes it worse. It also does little to nothing to reduce consumerism’s environmental
footprint (mining, soil fertility, plastic crap, toxins etc.), except on the
carbon-emissions side.
Consumerism, a.k.a. the inevitable
Cancer Stage of Capitalism, is the wrong economic model for current
realities, regardless of Grexit, Euro success, austerity, government-side economic stimulation and so on.
We are already asking too much of the
state and in pursuit of the impossible anyway: perpetual growth. For systemic reasons we cannot ask
the state to carry 100%, or 90%, or 80% etc. of the economy. Indeed, 50% is probably too high for systemic reasons, and I believe some countries are steadily approaching that figure.
Neoliberals probably want to see it down at 10 or 20%, but purchasing power would collapse.
As ever, short-termism prevails in the desperation austerity has wrought,
medium-term thinking is the best we can do in the circumstances, and that at the fringes of political
and business activity. We will thus stay mired in this systemic problem (absent little, short-lived growth spurts here and there) until the underlying perpetual
growth dynamic and the boundary conditions I set out here are seriously, openly
and wisely discussed right across the planet, and until radical change is
pursued. Syriza appears not to want to address this and is thus nowhere near radical enough, though I commend them for their courage and integrity.
* From
Bloomberg:
Banks may now be less reluctant to pass on negative rates to clients thanks to surplus liquidity.“Banks don’t have a need for deposits, and the demand for loans by households and firms is weak,” Niels Storm Stenbaek, chief economist at the Danish Bankers Association, said in a phone interview.
“[T]hanks
to surplus liquidity” references quantitative easing. There’s a tonne of money
out there in commerial bank accounts. Consequently, banks no longer need
customer deposits, and on top of that demand for debt is weak. Banks are making
huge profits nevertheless, not by lending to the private sector, but by gambling all
that high-powered money on the markets. This explains the divorce between
market boom and real-economy malaise.
In France, Toby, during the boom period of socialism, which is to say up until around 15 years ago, or so, many people saw pie in the sky as becoming a government employee. That meant job SECURITY, great benefits, early retirement in many sectors (not that early retirement is paradise, but we won't go into that here). Excellent working conditions, respect, because France rather liked the State at the time...
ReplyDeleteThe middle class, instead of banking that its children would go into the priesthood, saw them as government employees, in one form or another (lots of different levels of prestige in government employment, too...).
The middle class passed its children from the State sponsored schools into State sponsored employment, and the whole thing looked a lot like... the Church's organization, Toby...
But with important differences, nevertheless.
Ironically enough, you would have to live here for a long time to understand just how little the country really understands commerce, as opposed to capitalism, or consumerism.
Because there remains a formidable taboo against money in France, AND making it.
Incredible, but it's still here after all these centuries...
I don't entirely agree with your understanding of the money system, e.g., loans are not made against reserves. An empirical study by the Federal Reserve back in the 1980s demonstrated that loans are made first and then reserves follow a three to six months later.
ReplyDeleteOther than that, there is some good thinking here. If you add in some historical context and recognize that the true elites are transnational, it is pretty easy to see that the concept of a state as a protector and servant of its citizens has been turned on its head, and that what we call austerity today is really wholesale robbery of the average citizen to keep the elites comfortable.
Hi guys,
ReplyDeleteSorry, very busy, lots of work on since I got back from SE Asia.
Debbie, you're right imo to point out security. My reading is that we don't know what to do, culturally and socially at the large, institutional scale, with the fact that we could now have economic security for all, the potential is really there. The entire edifice and dynamic of how we got here presumes scarcity, insoluble and fundamental competition and struggle at the material level. My argument is that without consumerism, with flatter (less hierarchical) social systems and institutions, more sensible work arrangements, wiser and more nuanced ideas about value, reward, success, profit and producivity, there'd be no reason for anyone to suffer materially anywhere on earth. MATERIALLY. There's always going to be tragedy, challenge, risk, suffering etc., but materially there's enough to go around IF we organise sytems to that end.
Tao, that's not my understanding, that's the text-book definition (I think I'll add something to make that clear). My point was to go along with it to point out its vacuity in the face of real-world challenges, not to defend or vouch for it somehow. And I'd say the state has always been exploitative and extractive, that those phases where it seems to work for the People are against its grain. I've looked into this quite deeply, e.g. The Art of Not Being Governed, Debt: the First 5,000 Years, many other works by a wide variety of historians specifically on state formation and development and what a state really is, and studies into systems theory and living systems theory, and a bunch of other stuff too. Not just intuitive guess work by me. ;)